Friday, May 17, 2019

Decision Analysis

CREATE look into Archive Published Articles & musical themes 1-1-1980 Structuring Decision Problems for Decision Analysis Detlof von Winterfeldt University of southern California, emailprotected edu Follow this and additional works at http//research. form. usc. edu/published_papers Recommended Citation von Winterfeldt, Detlof, Structuring Decision Problems for Decision Analysis (1980). Published Articles & Papers. Paper 35. http//research. create. usc. edu/published_papers/35 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by CREATE Research Archive.It has been accepted for comprehension in Published Articles & Papers by an authorized administrator of CREATE Research Archive. For more(prenominal) in trackation, beguile contact emailprotected edu. Acta Psycho logica 45 (1980) 71-93 0 North-Holland Publishing Company STRUCTURING DECISION PROBLEMS FOR DECISION ANALYSIS * Detlof von WINTERFELDT ** University of southeasterlyern California, Los Angeles, CA 90007, USA Struc turing finding worrys into a form aloney acceptable and manageable format is probably the more or less big step of finish abbreviation.Since vexly no sound methodology for structuring exists, this step is withal an art leave to the intuition and craftsmanship of the individual analyst. After introducing a general concept of structuring, this paper reviews some natural advances in structuring research. These include taxonomies for trouble designation and new likewisels untold(prenominal) as solve diagrams and interpretative geomorphological elbow roomling. Two conclusions emerge from this review structuring research is still express mail to a a few(prenominal) hierarchical concepts and it tends to shorten substantive line aspects that delineate a business it its real world context.Consequently structuring research has little to evidence near distinctions amongst typic riddle classes such as regulation, siting, or cypher completelyocation. As an substit ute(a) the concept of prototypal termination uninflected expressions is introduced. Such structures ar developed to meet the substantive feature articles of a special line (e. g. , siting a precise quiet Natural Gas plant) but they ar at the same time general enough to apply to interchangeable puzzles (industrial facility siting). As an illustration, the development of a archetypal uninflected structure for environmental meter circumstance is described.Finally, some typic business classes atomic number 18 examined and some requirements for first structures ar dissertateed. An introduction to bother structuring Decision compend weed be carve up into four steps structuring the chore formulating inference and preference forms eliciting probabilities and utilities and exploring the numerical pretending results. Prac* This research was supported by a grant from the De fictional characterment of Defense and was monitored by the Engineering Psychology Program s of the Office of Naval Research, at a lower place contract NOOO14-79C-0529.While writing this paper, the author discussed the problem of structuring extensively with Helmut Jungermann. The present version owes a lot to his thought. Please entert take compose 3 too seriously. It is part of a footnote war between Ralph Keeney and me. ** Presently with the Social Science Research Institute, University of Southern California, University Park, Los Angeles, CA 90007, (213) 741-6955. 12 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring determination problems titioners of finding abstract generally agree that structuring is the most important and difficult step of the abstract.Yet, until recently, closing uninflected research has all but ignored structuring, concentrating instead on questions of role modeling and trigger. As a result, structuring was, and to some extent still is, considered the art part of determination analysis. This paper examines some attempts to binge this art into a cognition. Trees atomic number 18 the most common determination uninflectedal structures. Decision trees, for modelling, rede the sequential aspects of a decision problem (see Raiffa 1968 cook et al. 1974). Other examples be goal trees for the prototypes of grades (Keeney and Raiffa 1976) and event trees for the representation f inferential problem aspects (Kelly and Barclay 1973). In fact, trees so often dominate decision analytic structures that structuring is often considered synonymous to building a tree. This paper, however, exit adopt a more general notion of decision analytic structuring. According to this notion, structuring is an imaginative and original operate of translating an initially ill-defined problem into a set of welldefined genes, dealing, and operations. The basic structuring activities are delineateing or generating problem factors (e. g. , events, mensurates, actors, decision picks) nd relating these elements by influence relations, inclusi on relations, hierarchical ordering relations, etc. The structuring ferment seeks to formally represent the environmental (objective) parts of the decision problem and the decision makers or experts (subjective) views, opinions, and values. Graphs, maps, functional equations, matrices, trees, somatogenetic analogues, be given charts, and venn diagrams are all doable problem representations. In order to be useful structures for decision analysis, such representations must facilitate the subsequent steps of modeling, elicitation, and numerical nalysis. Three forms give the bounce be fall aparted in such a infer structuring process. In the first phase the. problem is place. The elements which are generated in this phase are the substantive features of the problem the decision maker(s) the generic classes of alternatives, objectives, and events individuals or groups affected by the decision characteristics of the problem environment. This list is pruned by answering questions such as what is the spirit of the analysis? For whom is the analysis to be performed? Which alternatives can the decision maker truly control?At this fix up only precise rough relations between problem elements are constructed. Examples include organizational relations D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 73 among decision makers, influence relations between classes of actions and events, and rough groupings of objectives. Products of this problem appellation step are usually not very formal, and are seldom reported in the decision analytic literature. They may be in the form of diagrams, graphs, or ordered lists. Among the few documented examples are Hogarth et al. (1980) for the problem of city planning and Fischer and von Winterfeldt 1978) for the problem of backcloth environmental standards. In the second structuring step, an b crude oilersuit analytic structure is developed. The elements generated in this step are assertable analytic problem representations. Besides tree structures, these may include more decomposable structures previously developed for confusable problems such as screening structures for siting decisions or signal maculation structures for medical decision making. paradigmatic structures of alternative modeling orgasmes (e. g. , systems dynamics or linear planming) which could fit the problem should also be examined at this step 1 I.A creative activity in this structuring phase is to relate and combine part structures, e. g. , model structures with military rating structures, or decision trees of different actors. From the candidate structures and their combinations an overall structure is selected which is judged most representative of the problem and manageable for move on modeling and elicitation. Only a handful of analytic structures view been developed which are more complex than decision trees. Gardiner and Ford (in press) combined simulation and evaluation structures.Keeney (in press) developed decisi on analytic structure for the whole process of siting zip facilities. Von Winterfeldt (1978) constructed a generic structure for regulatory decision making. The tertiary structuring phase coincides with the more traditionalistic and limited notion of structuring. In this step the parts of the overall analytic structure are formalized in detail by refining the problem elements and relations place in the first step. This includes a detailed construction of decision trees, event trees, and goal trees. Linkages between part structures are established, e. g. between simulation and evaluation structures. Decision makers and groups affected by doable decisions are specify together with events or actions linking l Although such structures alternatives to decision analytic in the remainder of this paper. structures should be considered, I bequeath ignore 14 D. von Winterfeldt/Structuring decision problems them. Examples of this structuring step can be found in most decision analytic t extbooks. This iii step structuring process of identifying the problem, developing an analytic structure, and formalizing its detailed content seldom evolves in strict sequence.Instead, the process is recursive, with repeated trials and errors. Often the analyst decides on a special structure and by and by finds it either unmanageable for modeling or non-representative of the problem. The recognition that a structure needs refmement often follows the closing step of decision analysis, if numerical computations and sensitivity analyses point to places that deserve more detailed analysis. Knowing rough the recursive nature of the structuring process, it is good decision analysis practice to spend much effort on structuring and to keep an open brainpower about accomplishable revisions.The above characterization of the structuring process will be employ as a format to review the structuring literature. First, the use of problem taxonomies for the step of problem identification i s examined. Methods to select analytic approaches are w presentfore reviewed as possible back up for the second structuring step. Finally, some recent advances in formalizing part structures are discussed. * Two conclusions emerged from this review and motivated the subsequent sections of this paper (1) Although structuring research has much to say about analytic distinctions between decision problems and structures (e. . , whether a problem is multiattributed or not), it has little intention on substantive problem distinction (e. g. , the difference between a typical regulation problem and a typical investment problem). (2) Structuring research is still limited to a few, usually hierarchical concepts and operations. wildness is put on unbiased, operational and calculating machineized structuring. Little effort is spent on creating more complex combinations of structures that represent real problem classes. As an alternative, the concept of prototypical decision analytic struc tures is introduced.Such structures endure more contentedness and complexity than the usual decision trees or goal trees. They are developed to meet the substantive characteristics of a specific problem, but are at the same time general enough to apply to similar problems. As an illustration, IIASAs 21 development of a prototypical decision analytic 2 International Institute for employ Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria. D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 75 structure for environmental standard shot will be described. Finally, several typical classes of decision problems will be examined and some requirements or prototypical structures will be discussed. Taxonomies for problem identification The taxonomies described in the pursuance typically classify decision problems by analytic categories (e. g. , whether a problem is multiattributed or not) and they attempt to slice the universe of problems into mutually exclusive and exhaustive sets. The purpose of such ta xonomies is triplex to facilitate the identification of an un cognise element (e. g. , a medical decision problem) with a class of problems (eg. , diagnostic problem) and to aid the process of the Temptering classes in the problem taxonomy (e. . , diagnostic problems) with an analytic approach (e. g. , signal detection structures). Thus, by their own aspiration, problem taxonomies should be useful for the early phases of structuring decision problems. MacCrimmon and Taylor (1975) discuss on a rather general level the relationship between decision problems and solution strategies. Decision problems are sort out according to whether they are ill-structured or well-structured, depending on the extent to which the decision maker feels familiar with the initial verbalise of the problem, the terminal state, and the transformations equired to reach a desired terminal state. Three main factors contribute to ill-structuredness uncertainty, complexity, and conflict. For each syndicate M acCrimmon and Taylor discuss a number of solution strategies. These strategies include, for example, reductions of the perceptions of uncertainty, modeling strategies, discipline acquisition and processing strategies, and methods for restructuring a problem. Taylor (1974) adds to this sorting scheme four basic types of problems resource specification, goal specification, creative problems, and well structured problems (see fig. 1).Problem types are identified by the decision makers familiarity with the three subparts of the problem. Taylor discusses what types of decision strategies are appropriate for each of these problem categories, for example, brainstorming for creative problems and operations research type solutions for well structured problems. Howell and Burnett (1978) recently developed a taxonomy of tasks 16 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring Problem token Initial State decision problems Terminal State Transformation Type 1, Resource Specification Problems UnfamllIar Type 11, Goal Specification Problems Type III, Creative ProblemsType IV, Well-Structured Problems Varies Varies Unfamihar Varies Vanes familiar Unfamiliar Familiar Fig. 1. Types of problem structures (Taylor 1974). and types of events with the intention of assessing cognitive options for processing probabilistic education for each taxonomy element. Uncertain events are classified according to three dichotomies frequentistic not frequentistic known data generator unknown data generator process external internal to the observer. Task characteristics are complexity, picture (e. g. , real life us. laboratory), span of events, and result mode characteristics. For each vent/task combination Howell and Burnett discuss how different cognitive processes may be direct when making probability judgments. For example, in estimating frequentistic events with unknown data generators, availability heuristics may be operative. browned and Ulvila (1977) present the most comprehensive attempt yet to classify decision problems. Their taxonomy includes well over 100 possible characteristics. Decision problems are defined according to their substance and the decision process involved. Substantive taxonomic characteristics are mainly derived from the analytic properties of the situation, i. . , amount and type of uncertainty, and amount D. von Winterfeldt/Structuring decision problems 71 and types of stakes, types of alternatives. Only a few elements of this part of the taxonomy can be straightway related to problem content, i. e. , current vs. contingent decision, operating vs. information act. The taxonomic elements of the decision process refer mainly to the constraints of the decision maker, e. g. , reaction time, available resources. The taxonomy by Brown and Ulvila incorporates most previous problem taxonomies which tried to define decision problems by categories derived from decision analysis.These include taxonomies by von Winterfeldt and Fischer (1975), Miller et al. ( 1976), and Vlek and Wagenaar (1979). To be useful for problem identification, the above taxonomies should lead an analyst to a class of problems which has characteristics similar to the decision problem under(a) investigation. Unfortunately, the existing problem taxonomies are ill-suited for this purpose, because they use mainly analytic categories to distinguish problems. Such categories are derivatives of the decision analytic models and concepts, rather than characteristics of real world problems. For example, the analytic categorizations f problems into precarious vs. riskless classes is based on the distinction between riskless and risky preference models. Analytic categories create more or less rescind classes with little or no correspondence to real problems. For example, none of the above taxonomies allows distinguishing between a typical siting problem and a typical regulation problem in a meaningful way. It appears that substantive rather than analytic characteristics i dentify real problems. Substantive characteristics are generalized content features of the problems belonging to the respective class. For example, a substantive eature of regulation problems is the involvement of three generic decision makers the regulator, the regulated, and the beneficiary of regulation. To become useful for problem identification, taxonomies need to include such substantive problem characteristic& Methods for selecting an overall analytic structure Most taxonomies include some ideas or principles for matching lems with analytic structures or models. MacCrimmon and attempted to match their basic type of decision problems with tive solution strategies, Howell and Burnett speculated on which tive processes may be invoked by typical task/event classes in probTaylor ognicogniproba- 18 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems bility assessment von Winterfeldt and Fischer identified for each problem category appropriate multiattribute benefit models. But in none of these papers explicit matching principles or criteria for the goodness of a match are given. Rather, matches are created on the basis of a priori reasoning about the appropriateness of a dodging, model, or a cognitive process for a incident class of decision problems. Brown and Ulvila (1977) attempted to make this pick process more explicit by creating an analytic taxonomy in correspondence with the problem taxonomy.The analytic taxonomy classifies the main options an analyst may have in structuring and modeling a decision problem. The taxonomy includes factors such as users options (amount to be expended on the analysis), input structure (type of uncertainty), elicitation proficiencys (type of probability elicitation). These categories identify options, both at a general level (optimization, simulation, and Bayesian inference models) and superfluous techniques (e. g. , reference gambles, or Delphi technique). To match problems with analytic approaches Brown and Ulvila c reated a third taxonomy, called the surgical process measure taxonomy.This taxonomy evaluates analytic approaches on attributes like time and cost measures, quality of the option generation process, quality of talk or implementation, etc. Different problem classes have different priority profiles on the proceeding measure categories. Similarly, different analytic approaches have different scoring profiles on the performance measures. The analytic approach chosen should perform well on the priority needs of a particular problem, Brown and Ulvila discuss the goodness of fit of several analytic approaches to a number of decision situations in basis of these performance measures.For example, they argue that a possibility type analysis (an element of the analytic taxonomy) is appropriate for decision problems that eliminate repeatedly and require a fast response (elements of the decision situation taxonomy) because contingency type analysis allows fast calculations (elements of th e performance measure taxonomy). Several authors have developed logical selection schemes, which can identify an appropriate analytic approach or model based on selected MacCrimmon (1973), for example, developed a problem features. sequential method for selecting an appropriate approach for multiattrib&e evaluation.The first question to be answered is whether the purpose of the analysis is normative or descriptive. Further questions D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 79 include whether the type of problem has occurred frequently before, if there are multiple decision makers with conflicting preferences, and whether alternatives are available or have to be designed. every last(predicate) questions are of the yes-no type and together create a flow chart for selecting among 19 possible approaches. For example, if the purpose of the analysis is normative, if direct assessments of preferences (e. g. ratings) are valid and reliable, and if the type of problem has frequent ly occurred before, regression models or analysis of variance type approaches would be appropriate. Johnson and Huber (1977) and Kneppreth et al. (1977) discuss a three step procedure for selecting a multiattribute utility assessment approach. In the first step, the characteristics of the multiattribute problem are listed, including discreteness vs. continuity of dimensions, uncertainty vs. no uncertainty, and independence considerations. In the second step the evaluation situation is characterized on the basis of judgments about the task complexity, mount of educational activity required for assessment, face validity required, assessment time, accuracy and flexibility. In the third and final step the profile describing the evaluation problem is compared with a profile characterizing five different generic assessment models or methods. The technique that best matches the situation profile is selected. For example, lottery assessment methods and models would be appropriate if the ev aluation problem involves uncertainties, does not require high face validity, and allows for a good amount of training of the assessor. Both the taxonomy riented and the sequential selection methods for matching problems and analysis suffer from certain overhaulbacks. As stated earlier, problem characteristics used in taxonomies typically dismiss substantive aspects of the decision problem. Consequently, an analyst may choose an analytic approach based on a match with a spuriously defined problem class. For example, when facing a medical diagnosing problem, an analyst may find that some detailed substantive characteristics of the problem (e. g. , the way doctors process information, the physical format of information, etc. ) argue a signal detection structure.Yet, as far as I can see, none of the above matching processes would directly lead to such a structure. Advances in formalizing structures forge diagrams are a recent development in decision analytic structuring (see Miller et al. 1976). modulate diagrams draw a graphical 80 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems picture of the way variables in a decision model influence each other, without superimposing any hierarchical structure. For example, a decision variable (price) may influence a state variable (demand) and thus influence a final state (successful introduction of a new product into market). Influence diagrams have been conceived mainly as an initial pre-structuring tool to create a cognitive map of a decision makers or experts view of a decision problem. In the present stage influence diagrams are turned into hierarchical structures and analyzed with traditional tools. But research is now underway at SRI International on the use of influence diagrams directly in EV or EU computations. Another generalization of the tree approach is Interpretative structural Modeling ( ism) developed, for example, in Warfield (1974) and Sage (1977). In interpretative structural modeling, matrix and graph heory notions are used to formally represent a decision problem. First, all elements of the problem are listed and an element by element matrix is constructed. The structure of the relationships between elements is whence constructed by filling in the matrix with numerical judgments reflecting the authorization of the relationship, or by simply making O-l judgments about the existence/non-existence of a relation. Computer programs can then be used to convert the matrix into a graph or a tree that represents the problem. Influence diagrams, value trees, decision trees, and inference trees can all be thought of as special encases of ISM.For example, in value tree construction, the analyst may begin with a rather arbitrary collection of value relevant aspects, attributes, outcomes, targets and objectives. Using alternative semantic labels for the relationships between these elements (e. g. , similar, part of), an element by element matrix can be filled. Finally, the analyst ca n explore whether a particular relational structure leads to useful goal tree structure. Besides these generalizations of traditional hierarchical structuring tools, several refinements of special structuring techniques have been suggested, curiously for evaluation roblems. Keeney and Raiffa (1976) devoted a whole chapter to the problem of structuring a value tree. They suggest a strategy of constructing a value tree by beginning with general objectives and disaggregating by using a everlasting(a) explication logic (i. e. , what is meant by this general objective? ). This approach has previously been advocated by Miller (1970) and others. Mannheim and Hall (1967) suggest in addition the possibility of disaggregating general D. van Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 81 objectives according to a means-ends logic (how can this general objective be achieved? ).Other disaggregation logics (problem oriented, process oriented, etc. ) could be analyzed in the ISM context. thither are a number of papers that suggest more empirical or man-made approaches to value tree construction. Of particular interest is a repertory grid technique described by Humphreys and Humphreys (1975) and Humphreys and Wisuda (1979). In this procedure similarity and dissimilarity judgments are used to span the value dimensions of alternatives. Several computer aids have been developed recently to aid decision makers or experts in structuring decision problems. most of these are discussed in Kelly ( 1978), and Humphreys (1980).These aids typically rely on empty structuring concepts (decison trees, value trees, inference trees, or influence diagrams) and they guide the decision maker/expert in the analytic formulation of his/her problem. Special aids are OPINT for moderately complex problems which can easily be formulated into a decision tree or matrix structure, the decision triangle aid for sequential decision problems with a focus on changing probabilities, and EVAL for multiattrib ute utility problems (Kelly 1978). In addition to these structuring and assessment aids, there are now computerized aids under development xploiting the idea of influence diagrams and fuzzy set theory. Influence diagrams, ISM, and computer aids are revelatory of a trend in structuring research and perhaps in decision analysis as a whole. This trend turns the fundamentally empty structures of decision trees, goal trees, and inference trees into more operational, computerized elicitation tools, without adding problem substance. There are clear advantages to such an approach a extensive range of applicability, flexibility, user involvement, speed, limited training, and feedback, to urinate only a few. It also reduces the demands on the decision analysts time.There is, of course, the other extreme, the prestructured, precanned problem specific version of decision analysis applicable to essentially identical situations. A military example is Decisions and Designs Inc. % SURVAV model ( Kelly 1978) which applies to routing decisions for ships to avoid detections by satellites. Such a structure and model can routinely be utilise with almost no additional training. In turn it gives up generalizability. Neither extreme is naturally satisfactory. exhaust general structures must consider each problem from scratch. Substantive specific struc- 82 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring ecision problems tures have limited generalizability. The middleground of problem driven but still generalizable structures and models needs to be filled. Problem taxonomies may help here by identifying generic classes of problems. But as was discussed earlier, existing taxonomies are ill equipped for this task since they neglect substantive problem features. The question of filling in the middleground between too general structures and too specific structures thus becomes a question of searching for generalizable content features of problems that identify generic classes of decisions.These gene ric classes can then be modelled and structured by prototypical decision analytic structures which are specific enough to match the generalizable problem features and general enough to transfer easily to other problems of the same class. At the present stage of research this search process will necessarily be inducive because too little is known about problem substance to develop a problem driven taxonomy and matching analytic structures. An inductive research strategy may attempt to crystallize the generalizable features of a specific application, . or compare a number of similar applications (e. . , with siting problems), or simply use a phenomenological approach to delineate problem classes in a specific application area (e. g. , regulation). In the following two sections some possibilities for developing prototypical decision analytic structures will be discussed. An example of developing a prototypical structure The following example describes the structuring process in the dev elopment of a decision aiding system for environmental standard compass and regulation. The work was performed as part of IIASAs (see fn. 2) standard setting project (see von Winterfeldt et al. 1978), which had oth descriptive and normative intentions (how do regulators presently set standards? how can analytic models help in the standard setting process? ). Because of this wide approach of the standard setting project, the research group was not forced to produce workable models for specific decision problems quickly. Consequently, its members could afford and were encouraged to spend a substantial amount of time on structuring. Inputs into the structuring process were retrospective case studies of specific mental protection agencies standard processes of environ- national Railway Corporation energylevelmeasure 3 measurefor aeroplane to-do 1 Japanese dB SO, AT SOURCE RULES ROUTING USE SCHEMES SCHEMES LAND Fig. 2. Regulatory alternatives for Shinkansen noise taint. IMPLEMENTATIO N AND MEASUREMENT INSTRUMENT /I ALTERNATIVE OF HOUSE IN HOUSE IN bet lMldB(A) WCPNLl MEAS6iiA 30 d&i) MEASURED LEO EQUIP- TION FICA- SPECI- MENT SPED CONTROL RES+RlCT TIMES OPERATION 84 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems previous models suggested for standard setting field studies of two ongoing standard setting processes (oil pollution and noise standards).In addition, the structuring process benefited much from continuing discussions with leading members of environmental agencies in the united Kingdom, Norway, Japan and the United States. Although the structuring effort was geared towards decision analysis, substantial inputs were given by an environmental economist (D. Fischer), an environmental modeller (S. Ikeda), a wager theorist (E. Hopfinger), and two physicists (W. Hafele and R. Avenhaus), all members of IIASAs standard setting research team. The overall question was how can standard setting problems best be formulated nto a decision analytic format and model such that the model is specific enough to capture the main features of a particular standard setting problem and, at the same time, general enough to apply to a variety of such problems? In other words, what is a prototypical decision analytic structure for standard setting? Since the regulator or regulatory agency was presumed to be the main client of such models, the initial structuring focussed on regulatory alternatives and objectives. In one attempt a wide but shallow alternative tree was conceived which included a variety of regulatory ptions ranging from emission standards, land use schemes, to direct interventions. An example for noise pollution standards is presented in fig, 2. Coupled with an appropriate tree of regulatory objectives, a decision analysis could conceivably be performed by evaluating each alternative with a simple MAU procedure. A possible value tree is presented in fig. 3 for the same noise pollution problem. This simple traditional structure was sp urned since regulators seldom have to evaluate such a wide range of alternatives and because it does not capture the fundamental interaction between the regulators and the regulated.Also, regulators are much concerned about monitoring and implementation of standards, an aspect which a simple MAU structure does not address. The second structure was a narrow but deep decision tree, exemplified in fig. 4 for an oil pollution problem. In addition to the regulators alternatives, this tree includes responses of the industriousness to standards, possible detection of standards violations, and subsequent sanctions. This structure was geared at fine tuning the regulators definitions of D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 85 of hospitals, schools, retwement homes besmirch f residential life DISTURBANCE other / EEggF M,NIM,zE HEALTH Hearing EFFECTS PsychologIcal synergetic (aggravation of existing illness) Investment for pollution equipment MINIMIZE COST Operation of pollutio n eqwpment RAILWAY CORP. OBJECTIVES Speed maximize SERVICE - Aeliablllty ClXlllOrt wth mtemational regulation CONSISTENCY OF REGULATION with other national cise standards (car, mr. other trams) POLITICAL OBJECTIVES -/ Enwonmental policy harmony POLICY WITH GOVERNMENT Transportation policy t Ewnomtc growih policy Fig. 3. Regulatory objectives for noise pollution control. he standard level (maximum emission, etc. ) and monitoring and sanction schemes, and to assessing environmental impacts. The structure is specific in terms of the regulatory alternatives. But by considering industry responses as random events, and by leaving out responses of environmental groups, it fails to address a major concern of regulatory decision making. The third structure was a three decision maker model, in which the regulator, the industry/developer and the environmentalists/impactees are represented by separate decision analytic models (see von Winterfeldt 1978).A signal detection type model links the regulators decision through possible detections of violations and sanction schemes to the the industry model. An event tree of pollution generating events and effects links the developers decisions to the impactee model (see fig. 5). The model can be run as follows the regulators alternatives are left 86 EPA norm UK aver,, UK maximum Norway average DEFINITIONS OF OIL EMISSION STANDARDS parts per million ofoil No pollution Grawty Separator c&ugated Plate Inter- equipment Gas Flotation Filters ceptrr n ob STANDARD LEVEL in watt r ofoil defilement EQUIPMENT PERFORMANCE o00 patis per milhon in water n First vidabon of No udaton of standard occurs at tulle DETECTION STATES standard dunng all opemons n t POLLUTION EQUIPMENT DECISION BY THE OIL manufacturing PENALTY No pdlution equipment Gravity separator Gas Flotatux corrugated Plate bltw- Pais Filters EQUIPMENT PERFORMANCE per million n Second wdation POLLUTION EQUIPMENT DECISION BY THE OIL INDUSTRY No more vidations DETECTION STATES square up eflects on environment (pdlution levels) FINAL EFFECTS industry (cost) regulatlx (political) Fig. 4. Segment of a decision tree for setting oil pollution standards. A standard is usually defined by the number of samples to be taken, how galore(postnominal) samples form an average, and how many exemptions from a violation are allowed. For example, the EPA average definition is as follows four samples are to be taken daily, the average of the four samples may not exceed the standard level (e. g. , 50 ppm) more than twice during any consecutive 30 day period. 87 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems REGULATORY 1 DECISION MODEL I U R (0 1 DETECTION OF REGULATION VIOLATION DEVELOPER SANCTIONS POLLUTION GENERATING EVENTS I IMPACTEE DECISION MODELPOLLUTION EFFECTS Fig. 5. Schematic representation of the regulator-developer-impactee model. 1 variable standard of the regulator d(r) evaluate utility maximizing treatment decision of the developer ad(r) expected util ity maximizing decision of the impactees variable. The developers response is optimized in terms of minimizing expected investment, operation, and detection costs or maximizing equivalent expected utilities. Finally, the impactees are assumed to maximize their expected utility conditional on the regulators and the developers decision. At this point the model stops.The structure only provides for a Pareto optimality analysis of the three expected utilities accruing to the generic decision units. This model allows some detailed analyses of the probabilities and value aspects of the standard setting problem, and it proved feasible in a pilot application to chronic oil discharge standards (see von Winterfeldt et al. 1978). Regulators who were presented with this model, con- 88 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems REGULATORS pickaxe Fig. 6. Game theoretic structure of the regulation I problem. sidered it meaningful, and it offered several insights into the standard setting problematique.Yet, there was a feeling among analysts and regulators that the static character of the model and the lack of feedback loops required improvement. The final structure considered was a game theoretic extension of the three decision maker model. The structure of the game theoretic model is presented in fig. 6. In this model the standard setting process in explicitly assumed to be dynamic, and all feedbacks are considered. In addition, transitions from one stage to another are probabilistic. The model was applied in a seven stage version in a pilot study of noise standard setting for rapid trains (Hapfinger and von Winterfeldt 1978).The game theoretic model overcomes the criticisms of the static decision analytic model, but in turn it gives up the possibility for fine tuning and detailed modeling of trade-offs and probabilities. Considering such aspects in detail would have made the running of the model impossible. Therefore, relatively arbitrary (linear) utility function s and simple structures of transition probabilities have to be assumed. Although the appropriateness of the different structures was not explicitly addressed in this study, two main criteria come to mind when judging structures representativeness of the problem and manageability for further analysis.Each of these criteria can be further broken down. For example, representativeness includes judgments about the sufficiency of the structural detail, and coverage of important problem aspects. The overall conclusions of many discussion with regulators, analysts, D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 89 industry representatives, and the results of the pilot applications led us to accept the third structure as a prototypical decision analytic structure for relatively routine emission standard setting problems. The model is presently considered for further applications in emission tandard setting and an extension to safety standards will be explored. Towards a kit of prototypic al decision analytical structures Not every decision analysis can afford to be as broad and time consuming as the previous study. Decision analysis usually has a much more specific orientation towards producing a decision rather than developing a generic structure. mollify I think that it would be helpful if analysts were to make an effort in addressing the question of generalizability when modeling a specific problem, and in extracting those features of the problem and the model that are transferable. Such an inductive pproach could be coupled with more research oriented efforts and with examinations of similarities among past applications. Such an approach may eventually fill the middleground between too specific and too general models and structures. But rather than filling this middleground with analytically specific but substantively empty structures and models, it would be filled with prototypical structures and models such as the above regulation model, more refined signal d etection models, siting models, etc. In the following, four typical classes of decision problems (siting, contingency planning, budget allocation, and regulation) are examined nd requirements for prototypical structures for these problems are discussed. Facility siting clearly is a typical decision problem. Keeney and other decision analysts have investigated this problem in much detail and in a variety of contexts (see the examples in Keeney and Raiffa 1976). A typical aspect of such siting problems is sequential screening from candidate areas to possible orders, to a preferred set, to final site specific evaluations. Another aspect is the multiobjective nature with emphasis on generic classes of objectives investment and operating cost, sparing benefits, environmental impacts, social impacts, and political onsiderations. Also, the process of organizing, collecting, and evaluating information is similar in many siting decisions. Thus, it should be possible to develop a prototypic al structure for facility siting decisions, 90 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems simply by make the generalizable features of past applications 31. Contingency planning is another recurring and typical problem. Decision and Design Inc. addressed this problem in the military context, but it also applies to planning for actions in the case of disasters such as Liquid Natural Gas plant explosions or blowouts from oil platforms.Substantive aspects that are characteristic of contingency planning are strong central control of executive organs, numerous decisions have to be made simultaneously, major events can drastically change the focus of the problem, no cost or low cost information comes in rapidly, and organizational problems may impede information flows and actions. Although, at first glance, decision trees seem to be a natural model for contingency planning, a prototypical decision model would require modifying a strictly sequential approach to accommodate these aspects.For example, the model should be flexible enough to allow for the unforeseeable (rapid electrical condenser to change the model structure), it should have rapid information updating facilities without overstressing the value of information (since most information is free), and it should attend to fine tuning of simultaneous actions and information interlinkages. Budget allocation to competing programs is another typical problem. In many such problems different programs attempt to pursue similar objectives, and program mix and balance has to be considered besides the direct benefits of single programs.Another characteristic of budgeting decisions is the continuous nature of the decision variable and the constraint of the total budget. MAU looks like a natural structure for budget allocation decision since it can handle the program evaluation aspect (see Edwards et al. 1976). But neither the balance issue nor the constrained and continuous characteristics of the budget are ap propriately adressed by MAU. A prototypical decision analytic structure would model an evaluation of the budget apportionment, or the mix of programs funded at particular levels.Such a structure would perhaps exploit dependencies or independencies among programs much like independence assumption for preferences. Regulation covers a class of decision problems with a number of repeated themes three generic groups involved (regulators, regulated, ,3 I believe that. Keeneys forthcoming book on siting energy facilities is a major step in that direction. Of. course, it could also be a step in the opposition direction. Or in no direction at all (see also first asterisked footnote at the beginning of the article). D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 91 beneficiaries of regulation), importance f monitoring and sanction schemes, usually oppose objectives of the regulated and the benefrciaries of regulation, and typically highly political objectives of the regulator. In the pre vious section, the more specific regulation problem of standard setting was discussed, and a prototypical decision analytic structure was suggested. A decision analytic structure for regulation in general can build on the main features of the standard setting model. This list could be extended to include private investment decisions, product mix selection, resource development, diagnostic problems, etc. But the four examples hopefully re sufficient to demonstrate how prototypical decision analytic structuring can be approached in general. In my opinion, such an approach to structuring could be at least as useful for the implementation of decision analysis as computerization of decision models. Besides the technical advantages of trahsferability, prototypical decision analytic structures would serve to show that decision analysts are truly concerned about problems. at present decision analysis books have chapters such as simple decisions under uncertainty and multiattribute evaluati on problems. I am looking forward to chapters such as siting industrial acilities, pollution control management, and contingency planning. References Brown, R. V. and J. W. Ulvila, 1977. Selecting analytic approaches for decision situations. (Revised edition. ) Vol. I Overview of the methodology. Technical report no. TR77-7-25, Decisions and Designs, Inc. , McLean, VA. Brown, R. V. , A. S. Kahr and C. Peterson, 1974. Decision analysis for the manager. newfound York Holt, Rinehart, and Winston. Edwards, W. , M. Guttentag and K. Snapper, 1976. A decision-theoretic approach to evaluation research. In E. L. Streuning and M. Guttentag (eds. ), Handbook of evaluation research, I. London Sage.Fischer, D. W. and D. von Winterfeldt, 1978. Setting standards for chronic oil discharges in the North Sea. Journal of Environmental Management 7, 177-199. Gardiner, P. C. and A. Ford, in press. A merger of simulation and evaluation for applied policy research in social systems. In K. Snapper (ed. ), Practical evaluation case studies in simplifying complex decision problems. Washington, DC Information Resource Press. Hogarth, R. M. , C. Michaud and J. -L. Mery, 1980. Decision behavior in urban development a methodological approach and substantive considerations. Acta Psychologica 45, 95-117. Hiipfmger, E. and R. Avenhaus, 1978.A game theoretic framework for . dynamic standard setting procedures. IIASA-RM-78. International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria. 92 D. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems Hopfinger, E. and D. von Winterfeldt, 1979. A dynamic model for setting railway noise standards. In 0. Moeschlin and D. Pallaschke (eds. ), Game theory and related topics. Amsterdam North-Holland. pp. 59-69. Howell, W. C. and S. A. Burnett, 1978. Uncertainty measurement a cognitrve taxonomy. Organizational Behavior and man Performance 22,45-68. Humphreys, P. C. , 1980. Decision aids aiding decisions. In L.Sjoberg, T. Tyszka and J. A. Wise (eds), De cision analyses and decision processes, 1. Lund Doxa (in press). Humphreys, P. C. and A. R. Humphreys, 1975. An investigation of subjective preference orderings for multiattributed alternatives. In D. Wendt and C. Vlek (eds. ), Utility, probability, and human decision making. Dordrecht, Holland Reidel, pp. 119-133. Humphreys, P. C. and A. Wisudha, 1979. MAUD an interactive computer program for the structuring, rotting and recomposition of preferences between multiattributed alternatives. Technical report 79-2, Decision Analysis Unit, Brunel University, Uxbridge, England.Johnson, E. M. and G. P. Huber, 1977. The technology of utility assessment. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, vol. SMCJ, 5. Keeney, R. L. , in press. Siting of energy facilities. New York Academic Press. Keeney, R. L. and H. Raiffa, 1976. Decisions with multiple objectives preferences and value tradeoffs. New York Wiley. Kelly, III, C. W. , 1978. Decision aids engineering science and clinical art. Technical Report, Decisions and Designs, Inc. , McLean, VA. Kelly, C. and S. Barclay, 1973. A general Bayesian model for hierarchical inference. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 10, 388-403.Kneppreth, N. P. , D. H. Hoessel, D. H. Gustafson, and E. M. Johnson, 1977. A strategy for selecting a worth assessment technique. Technical paper 280, U. S. Army Research Institute for Behavioral and Social Sciences, Arlington, VA. MacCrimmon, K. R. , 1973. An overview of multiple criteria decision making. In J. L. Cochrane and M. Zeleney (eds. ), Multiple criteria decision making. Columbia, SC The University of South Carolina Press. pp. 18-44. MacCrimmon, K. R. and R. N. Taylor, 1975. Problem solving and decision making. In M. C. Dunnette (ed. ), Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology. New York Rand McNally.Mannheim, M. L. and F. Hall, 1967. Abstract representation of goals a method for making decisions in complex problems. In Transportation, a service. Proceedings o f the Sesquicentennial Forum, New York academy of Sciences American Society of Mechanical Engineers, New York. Miller, J. R. , 1970. Professional decision making a procedure for evaluating complex alternatives. New York Praeger. Miller, AC. , M. W. Merkhofer, R. A. Howard, J. E. Matheson and T. R. Rice, 1976. Development of automated aids for decision analysis. Technical report, Stanford Research Institute, Menlo Park, CA. Raiffa, H. , 1968. Decision analysis.Reading, MA Addison-Wesley. Sage, A. , 1977. methodology for large scale systems. New York McGraw-Hill. Taylor, R. C. , 1974. Nature of problem ill-structuredness implications for problem formulation and solution. Decision Sciences 5,632-643. Vlek, C. and W. A. Wagenaar, 1979. Judgment and decision under uncertainty. In J. A. Michon, E. G. Eijkman and L. F. W. DeKlerk (eds. ), Handbook of psychonomics, II. Amsterdam North-Holland. pp. 253-345. Warfield, J. , 1974. Structuring complex systems. Batelle Memorial Institute Monog raph, no. 4. Winterfeldt, D. von, 1978. A decision aiding system for improving the environmental standardD. von Winterfeldt /Structuring decision problems 93 setting process. In K. Chikocki and A. Straszak (eds. ), Systems analysis applications to complex programs. Oxford Pergamon Press. pp. 119-124. Winterfeldt, D. von and D. W. Fischer, 1975. Multiattribute utility models and scaling procedures. In D. Wendt and C. Vlek (eds. ), Utility, probability, and human decision making. Dordrecht, Holland Reidel. pp. 47-86. Winterfeldt, D. von, R. Avenhaus, W. Htiele and E. Hopfmger, 1978. Procedures for the establishment of standards. IIASA-AR-78-A, B, C. International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.